A very good friend of mine is putting together a venture capital fund devoted to "double bottom line" companies in financial services. In particular, this fund will invest in new business models for providing services to the "underbanked" (whom my friend quaintly insists on referring to as poor people). He's looking for people with a strong background in finance and investment who would be into this kind of thing. The job would be in New York. If you're interested, please write something about yourself to doublebottomline@yahoo.com. (Please don't write to me, I don't know anything more than I've already written.)

It's easy to be cynical about all this, and Interfluidity ain't a job site, but this is someone I know, and what he does he does well. My apologies for the ad-ish-ness. I promise not to make a habit of it.

Steve Randy Waldman — Friday June 6, 2008 at 12:54am permalink
anon:
You should do a post on Lacker's speech:

http://www.richmondfed.org/news_and_speeches/
presidents_speeches/index.cfm/id=107
6.6.2008 4:40am
Thomas Barker (www):
I am helping organise BarCampBankLondon on July 5th. We've got a lot of precipitants who are interested in using technology to reach "poor people". Including a very interesting "stealth" non-profit start-up...

We've had a lot of interest from UK banks. I think the industry here is starting to refocus from shuffling loans in and out of structured vehicles to doing more practical things :-)
6.6.2008 4:47pm
Thomas Barker (www):
Sorry for the further ad-iness. I'll write a considered comment on global CDO liquidity, or something, later to restore the balance :-)
6.6.2008 4:53pm
Steve Randy Waldman (mail) (www):
Anon:

Your wish is me command, but I didn't have anything original enough to add to make a post of this... it is almost all summary.

———

Central bankers are bright people. But when they speak, I'm often left with the impression of wonderful minds trapped, by position, by the weight of their words in financial markets, by a very human impulse to rationalize their role and past actions. In view of this, Richmond Fed president Jeffrey Lacker's speech last week was an unexpected delight. This week has seen a lot of Fed Kremlinology about Lacker's speech, about what it means that (gasp!) a Fed president said some things that might be interpreted as not entirely laudatory of Fed policy. Whatever. Lacker's remarks stand on their own as honest and thoughtful.

I'm late to this party, see, for example, Yves Smith, Scurvon, David Merkel, Barry Ritholtz, Michael Shedlock, and Justin Fox. Lacker's speech is not long. You should read the whole thing. Some highlights:

1. Lacker distinguishes between "nonfundamental" crises, self-fulfilling panics on sound institutions, and "fundamental" crises, creditors seek to withdraw funds because they have reason to believe that a bank will be unable to make good on all of its obligations. He suggests that while liquidity support may be appropriate for panics, government support in a "fundamental" crisis may be actively harmful.

2. Lacker points out that in the long run, the fragility of the banking system isn't due to housing prices or securitization, but due to the fact that the financial system by design promises more than it can deliver: Financial institutions fund long-term risky investments with short-term obligations represented as risk-free. (When a fiat-money central banker starts channeling moldbug, you know we are living in interesting times.)

3. Lacker's core insight is that this state of affairs is not "natural" or "necessary", but a function of the institutional environment we've established, largely by virtue of government guarantees. He suggests that absent promises of intervention, financial intermediaries and their customers would come up with contractual arrangements under which banks would restrict the customers' ability to redeem deposits en masse (presumably in exchange for higher interest payments). Fighting conventional wisdom, Lacker seems to think the fragility of "modern" banking systems isn't actually necessary, that people's appetite for risk would be sufficient to fund large-scale investment without having banks pretend that those investments are perfectly safe and liquid.

4. Lacker makes a subtle and profound point that "moral hazard" is less about the "due diligence" creditors might or might not perform than the contractual protections they might or might not demand. Lenders to nonfinancial firms insist on "covenants", contractual triggers that give lenders the right to withdraw funds or renogotiate higher rates if borrowers fail to meet certain safety requirements. Those contractual arrangements institutionalize market discipline. Investors needn't be expensively active about supervising borrowers affairs, because the covenants themselves are a technology of surveillance, an automated alarm system. When alarms are tripped, six-figure analysts must be deployed. But much of the time, the mere existence of the alarms is enough to encourage good behavior. With government guarantees in place for financial firms, there has been no incentive to develop contractual surveillance appropriate to bank borrowing. In theory, regulators offer protection, but in practice, that hasn't worked so well. Small depositors will probably always require a mix of guarantees and regulation (try attaching a covenant to your deposit of last week's paycheck). But without government guarantees, larger creditors might be as capable of imposing contractual surveillance as banks are clever at avoiding regulation. If policemen were perfect, no one would invent alarm systems. So long as bank creditors can assume that an infinite well of dollars at the Fed will be deployed on their behalf, why pay lawyers and bean counters to install financial motion sensors?

5. Lacker points out that, for market discipline to work, central bank threats to not cover losses must be credible. "If actions speak louder than words in the case of central bank credit policy as well, then the only credible way to limit expectations of future lending is to 'incur the risk of short-run disruptions in financial markets by disappointing expectations and by not lending as freely as before.'" In other words, as mean or Victorian or Austrian as it sounds, some creditors have to actually get hurt, and the Fed has to be sufficiently blasé about the consequences that market participants believe the Fed would let that happen again.

6. Lacker does not discuss the problem of institutions so large or crucial that threats of nonintervention could never be credible. Given recent history, that's a pretty big omission. Lacker doesn't suggest that we eliminate the present system of guarantees and regulation, only that we contain it by delineating its scope and never extending guarantees beyond stated boundaries. But that doesn't strike me as practical. Unregulated institutions would find ways of making themselves indispensable, and creditors would prefer tacit guarantees to the costs of imposing surveillance. Lacker's logic requires that regulation and guarantee automatically attach to scale and interconnectedness, and that regulation be draconian so that unregulated firms could compete for funds without the government subsidy. In other words, we would need to move to a "narrow banking" sector that takes on very little risk, and an unregulated sector whose members are prevented from getting big. That's a direction I like, but Lacker doesn't go there. He seems to suggest that we could draw sharper lines and then hang tough without imposing major structural changes. I don't buy that.

Overall, this was an excellent speech. Do read the original. And thank you, Jeffrey Lacker.
6.8.2008 10:17am
anon:
Thanks for the review.

Yes, Moldbug might have something to say (volumes probably) about the maturity transformation discussion.

The most intriguing part of the speech for me was the following (in relation to Bear Stearns):

"Moral hazard is the central problem that the financial safety net necessarily brings with it. And this problem exists even if central bank lending ensures that the resolution of a problem institution leaves its shareholders with nothing. Market discipline on risk-taking by financial firms comes more from the cost of debt finance than from equity holders (given the limited liability nature of equity). So it is the potential consequences of central bank lending for creditors that raises moral hazard concerns by reducing the cost of debt and potentially leading to greater leverage than would otherwise be chosen."
6.8.2008 9:55pm
Note: You don't have to register to comment! Just use the pull-down menu to comment as "Guest".

Post as: [Register] [Log In]

Account:
Password:
Remember info?